IV. Legal aspects of price discrimination
While price discrimination is widely accepted by economists and marketers, the legal community has expressed concerns about it for a considerable duration. The main reason behind the desire to restrict price discrimination stems from the concept of fairness: Is it equitable to charge different prices for the same product or service? [1] To address this question, delving into the philosophical debate surrounding fairness is a topic I will reserve for another occasion. In this context, I will focus on the two main aspects that can render price discrimination illegal – constitutional and antitrust considerations.
People often assume that price discrimination is automatically unconstitutional when they hear the word "discrimination." However, this is not always the case. There has long been debate about the extent to which the Constitution provides protection and for whom. The Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment guarantees “the equal protection of the law” to every person, primarily encompassing protection against discrimination based on gender, race, or national origin. Nevertheless, some states may offer more extensive protection than what the U.S. Constitution provides.
For example, California has adopted a more comprehensive approach than any other state by enacting the Gender Tax Repeal Act of 1995, which prohibits price discrimination based on gender. However, while acknowledging the potential challenges and added costs associated with providing services that may vary by a client's gender, the law permits different pricing when it can be justified by factors such as the amount of time, complexity, or expenses involved in delivering the service. So, if you are an esthetician specializing in waxing, charging different prices for Brazilian waxing for women and men is generally not permitted unless you can provide a valid justification based on the additional time required for the procedure.
Furthermore, antitrust and price-fixing laws render price discrimination illegal in certain situations. There are three primary antitrust acts worth mentioning in this context: the Sherman Antitrust Act, the Clayton Antitrust Act, and the Robinson-Patman Act.
The Clayton Antitrust Act, for instance, was enacted by Congress with the specific aim of prohibiting price discrimination, especially when a company engages in predatorily low pricing tactics that could lead to market monopoly. Subsequently, the Clayton Act was further amended with the Robinson-Patman Act. This amendment took a different approach by addressing the competitive advantage enjoyed by larger grocery chains over smaller competitors who were losing business due to the lower prices offered by the larger retailers. These larger chains operated more efficiently and had access to lower procurement prices through bulk purchases.
However, nowadays, the Robinson-Patman Act has become less influential, and courts have become hesitant to rule against the defendant retailer without strong economic evidence of affecting a competitor adversely. Even though the Act aimed to protect smaller retailers, its impact has waned in recent times.